Theory of Demand
- Theory of Demand
- Effective demand
- 🤔 What makes Demand Effective?
- 📊 Demand Schedules/Curves
- 👤 Individual Demand Schedules and Individual Demand
- 🛒 Market Demand Schedules and Market Demand
- Total and Marginal Utility
- We can illustrate this formally with this table:
- Let’s graph this table below:
- Deeper Explanation:
- Deriving Demand Curves
- Demand curve derived using marginal utility
- Demand curve derived using income effect
- The Income Effect Explained:
- Demand curve derived using substitution effect
- 🚀 Exceptions to the Law of Demand
- Exceptions to the law of demand graph:
- Knowledge checkpoint: Answer these actual Higher Economics exam questions:
- Understanding Demand Curves
- Movements Along Demand Curves
- let’s take Black Friday Sales as an example
- Causes of Shifts in Demand Curves
- let’s explore how these determinants of demand can shift the demand curve to the right:
- let’s explore how these determinants of demand can shift the demand curve to the left:
- Test Your Knowledge with Scenarios
- What is Price Elasticity of Demand (PED)?
- Elasticity affects the slope of a product's demand curve:
- How to calculate PED?
- Practice calculating the price elasticity of demand in these following examples:
- What are factors that can influence the PED of a product?
- Let’s explore each factors in more detail:
- Durability
- Habit-Forming Goods
- Availability of substitutes
- Percentage of Income Spent
- Degree of Necessity
- Other factors that can affect PED:
- Price Elasticity of Demand and Total Revenue
- Total revenue and Demand
- Let’s consider an example of where demand is elastic and there is a price DECREASE:
- Let’s consider an example of where demand is elastic and there is a price INCREASE:
- Let’s now consider an example of where demand is inelastic and there is a price DECREASE:
- Let’s now consider an example of where demand is inelastic and there is a price INCREASE:
- Let’s now consider an example of where demand is unit elastic:
- Summary:
- Knowledge checkpoint: Answer these actual Higher Economics exam questions:
Effective demand
This situation illustrates a concept in economics called effective demand. But what exactly is effective demand, and how does it relate to the demand schedules and curves that shape our buying decisions?
🤔 What makes Demand Effective?
1️⃣ A consumer needs to have a willingness to buy the item
2️⃣ A consumer needs to have the ability to buy the item
- Effective demand is the demand from consumers that is backed up with an ability to pay. It refers to the willingness and ability of consumers to purchase goods at different prices.
- When we think about the demand curve, we are thinking about effective demand.
📊 Demand Schedules/Curves
- A column that lists the price for a product in increasing or decreasing order.
- A column that lists the quantity of the product desired at that particular price.
- Individual Demand Schedule: Shows the demand of one customer for a particular good at various prices.
- Market Demand Schedule: Summation of individual demand schedules, representing the total demand in the market.
👤 Individual Demand Schedules and Individual Demand
- The x-axis represents demand while the y-axis represents the price of a given good
Let’s take Tesco’s finest shortbread as an example. There is a customer called Katy. Below we list the price for shortbread in increasing order and the individual quantity of the product desired. Here is an example of the individual demand schedule:
Point | Price per shortbread (£) | Katy’s Quantity Demanded |
a | 1 | 10 |
b | 1.5 | 8 |
c | 2 | 6 |
d | 2.5 | 4 |
e | 3 | 2 |
- At £1 per shortbread, Katy buys 10 shortbreads.
- At £2, she buys 6 shortbreads.
- At £3, she only buys 2 shortbreads.
🛒 Market Demand Schedules and Market Demand
- A graphical representation of the market demand schedule is called the market demand curve which is what you would have typically seen!
Suppose there are only 3 buyers of shortbread in the market – Katy, Ben and Nkechi. The market schedule and market demand curve can be seen below:
Market schedule:
Market demand curve:
Total and Marginal Utility
- Total Utility: The complete amount of satisfaction gained from consuming a certain quantity of goods.
- Marginal Utility: The satisfaction gained from consuming one additional unit of a good.
- Total Utility: This is the overall satisfaction you get from eating pizza. The first slice is amazing (high total utility!), and the second is pretty good too (adds to your total satisfaction), but maybe by the fifth slice, you're starting to feel full (lower total utility).
- Marginal Utility: This is the extra satisfaction you get from eating just one more slice. So, the first slice gives you a big boost in happiness (high marginal utility), but each additional slice adds a little less enjoyment (lower marginal utility).
We can illustrate this formally with this table:
Quantity (Slices of Pizza) | Total Utility | Marginal Utility |
1 | 10 | 10 |
2 | 18 | 8 |
3 | 24 | 6 |
4 | 28 | 4 |
5 | 30 | 2 |
6 | 30 | 0 |
7 | 28 | -2 |
- The first slice provides a big jump in satisfaction, reflected by high total utility (10) and marginal utility (10).
- As you eat more slices, total enjoyment keeps increasing (higher total utility), but by smaller amounts with each slice (decreasing marginal utility).
- At the 6th slice, you feel really full—you're no longer getting any additional enjoyment (marginal utility = 0) and your total utility is maximised at 30.
- By the 7th slice, you might even feel uncomfortable (negative marginal utility), meaning another slice decreases your overall satisfaction (total utility goes down)
Let’s graph this table below:
Deeper Explanation:
- Second Slice: If the marginal utility of the second slice is 8, it adds to the total utility from the first slice. So, 10 (from the first slice) + 8 (from the second slice) = 18 total utility.
- Always Decreasing: Marginal utility always decreases as you consume more. Each additional slice of pizza provides less satisfaction than the previous one.
- From the first to the second slice, total utility jumps from 10 to 18.
- From the third to the fourth slice, it increases from 24 to 28.
- By the 5th or 6th slice, your total utility is maximised at 30. After this point, eating more pizza doesn't add to your satisfaction (marginal utility = 0).
- By the 7th slice, your total utility decreases because the marginal utility becomes negative, meaning each additional slice actually reduces your overall satisfaction.
What does the green line from the graph remind you of? 👀
Deriving Demand Curves
Demand curve derived using marginal utility
As discussed, marginal utility (MU) is the satisfaction gained from consuming one additional unit of a good. We've already plotted our total utility against our marginal utility on a graph (are we able to link this graph here?).
If we wanted to plot a demand curve using marginal utility, we could replace the price on the Y-axis with MU and keep quantity on the X-axis just like we did on the left hand side above.
Interestingly, the marginal utility curve looks exactly like a demand curve. You might be wondering, why is this the case?
- First Slice: You're starving, so that first slice brings incredible satisfaction (high MU). You'd probably be willing to pay a high price for it because it solves a big problem (hunger).
- Second Slice: You're still hungry, but not quite as much. The second slice is still good (positive MU), but not quite as amazing as the first. You might be willing to pay a decent price for it, but not quite as much as the first.
- Third Slice: You're starting to get full, but another slice sounds nice. The MU is lower than the first two slices. You might pay a reasonable price, but it would have to be lower than the previous slices.
As you keep eating:
- Marginal Utility Keeps Decreasing: With each additional slice, you get less and less enjoyment (lower MU). Eventually, you might reach a point where another slice wouldn't be enjoyable at all (MU = 0).
- Willingness to Pay Decreases: Because the extra satisfaction (MU) from each slice keeps going down, you'd naturally be less willing to pay a high price for them. You might even stop buying pizza altogether if the price is too high compared to the little enjoyment you'd get (negative MU).
- Remember, we are trying to explain the law of demand in another way using marginal utility which is all about our satisfaction!
Say you have a favourite snack. if the price of the snack remains high, you might stop buying more after a few bites because the added satisfaction just isn't worth the cost.
However, if the price drops, you're more likely to keep buying more because even though each additional bite gives you less satisfaction, the lower cost makes it worth it.
This explains why consumers like you and me buy more units of a product only when the price goes down: the lower price compensates for the lower satisfaction gained from consuming each additional unit.
- This therefore explains using marginal utility why the demand curve slopes downwards!
Demand curve derived using income effect
Now, let's talk about how changes in prices can make you feel richer or poorer, affecting your demand.
Income Effect Definition: The income effect describes how a change in the price of a good affects the purchasing power of a consumer's income, leading to a change in the quantity demanded of that good.
The Income Effect Explained:
- Example: Imagine you have £10 to spend each day.
- If rice costs £3 per bag, and you spend £3 on rice, you have £7 left for other things.
- Price Drop: If the price of rice drops to £2 per bag, you still have your £10, but now you spend only £2 on rice and have £8 left over. It feels like you have more money, so you might buy more rice or other things.
- Price Increase: If the price of rice goes back up to £3, you spend £3 on rice again, leaving you with only £7 for other things. It feels like you have less money, so you might buy less rice or other things.
- Feeling Richer: When prices drop, you feel richer because your money goes further. This might make you want to buy more of the good whose price dropped or other goods.
- Feeling Poorer: When prices rise, you feel poorer because your money doesn’t go as far. This might make you want to buy less of the good whose price increased or other goods.
- Impact on Demand: This change in your purchasing power helps explain why demand for a product falls when its price rises. It becomes less affordable, so you buy less of it and vice versa.
Demand curve derived using substitution effect
The substitution effect definition: The substitution effect is the change in the quantity demanded of a good due to a change in its price, making it more or less attractive relative to other substitute goods.
- Substitute goods are products that can be used in place of each other
Let’s say pasta and rice both costs £5:
- Price Drop: If the price of rice falls to £3, rice becomes cheaper compared to pasta. Even if the price of pasta stays the same at £5, pasta now feels more expensive. You might buy more rice instead of pasta, increasing the quantity demanded for rice.
- Price Increase: If the price of rice rises to £6, pasta feels cheaper by comparison as its price remains at £5. You might switch from rice to pasta, reducing your demand for rice.
As one good becomes cheaper, we buy more of it instead of its substitutes, and vice versa. This effect also contributes to the downward slope of the demand curve:
🚀 Exceptions to the Law of Demand
However, there are some interesting exceptions to this rule and it is sometimes the case that the demand curve slopes upwards instead of downwards!
Let's explore a few of them.
Definition: Giffen goods involves low-income consumers purchasing more basic food products as prices increase, because they cannot afford to purchase anything else
Imagine you're buying a basic food item like bread. Normally, if the price of bread goes up, you'd buy less bread. But what if bread is such a big part of your diet that you can't afford to buy other foods when it gets more expensive?
In this case, you might actually end up buying more bread because it's still the cheapest way to get full. This kind of strange situation is what economists call a "Giffen good."
- Example: If a staple food like bread gets more expensive and your income doesn't change, you might have to spend more on bread and less on other foods, leading you to buy more bread instead of less.
Definition: Veblen goods involve consumers purchasing more of a good because it is well-known/expensive, to “show off”.
Now let's think about luxury items like designer clothes or fancy cars. Sometimes, people buy these items not just because they need them, but because they want to show off. If the price of these items goes up, they might actually become more desirable because owning them makes you look rich and successful. These are called "Veblen goods."
- Example: If the price of a luxury car increases, some people might want it even more because it shows they can afford something expensive, making it a status symbol.
Definition: Speculation is when consumers purchase more of a good when its price rises because they expect it to rise further in the future
Speculation is all about guessing what will happen to prices in the future and making decisions based on those guesses. Sometimes, if people think the price of something will go up in the future, they might buy more of it now, even if the current price is already high. This can create an exception to the law of demand.
- Example: If people believe the price of a certain stock is going to skyrocket, they might buy a lot of it now, even if it's already expensive, hoping to sell it for a profit later.
Definition: Anticipatory purchases occur when consumers buy more of a product as they expect its price to rise in the future.
Anticipatory purchases happen when consumers believe that the price of a product, like petrol before a budget announcement, might increase soon. This behaviour can lead to increased demand even before the price actually rises.
- Example: Motorists might buy more petrol if they anticipate a price increase in an upcoming budget announcement.
Perceived quality and demand refer to situations where consumers associate high price with high quality, leading to increased demand.
When consumers perceive that a high price indicates superior quality, they may be willing to buy more of a product, even if its actual quality is not easily distinguishable.
- Example: Expensive shampoos like Aussie may see increased demand simply because consumers associate higher prices with better quality, regardless of the actual differences in product quality.
Exceptions to the law of demand graph:
- Giffen Goods: Necessities that people buy more of when prices rise, due to budget constraints on other items.
- Veblen Goods: Luxury items that become more desirable as their prices increase, due to their status symbol appeal.
- Speculation: Buying more of something now because you think its price will rise in the future, even if it's already expensive.
- Anticipation: Purchasing more of a product in anticipation of future price increases or scarcity, to benefit from current conditions or avoid higher costs later.
- Perceived Quality and Demand: When consumers associate higher prices with higher quality, leading to increased demand for goods perceived as premium, regardless of actual differences in quality.
These exceptions show that human behaviour can sometimes be unpredictable and doesn't always follow the simple rules of supply and demand!
Knowledge checkpoint: Answer these actual Higher Economics exam questions:
Understanding Demand Curves
A shift in the demand curve means that at the exact same price, consumers wish to buy more.
A movement along the demand curve occurs following a change in price.
Movements Along Demand Curves
let’s take Black Friday Sales as an example
- Increase in Quantity Demanded: Due to this price reduction, consumers who were previously hesitant to purchase the TV at £800 find the £500 price tag more attractive. As a result, they decide to buy the TV during the Black Friday sale.
- Analysing the Movement: On a demand curve graph, this situation is represented by a movement from a higher price point (£800) to a lower price point (£500), resulting in an increase in the quantity demanded. This movement occurs along the demand curve, assuming other factors affecting demand (such as consumer income, preferences, and prices of substitutes like projectors or larger TVs) remain constant during the sale period.
- Conversely, if the price were to increase from £800 to £1100, there would be a movement along the demand curve resulting in a decrease in the quantity demanded.
Expansion in demand. A fall in price from £800 to £500 leads to an expansion (increase) in demand. As price falls, there is a movement along the demand curve and more is bought from 80 to 100.
Causes of Shifts in Demand Curves
Definition: Determinants of demand are changes in conditions that cause the demand curve to shift either to the left or right.
You can use the mnemonic "ITAPFAPE" to remember the changes that can shift demand:
Income, Tastes, Advertising, Prices of other goods (substitutes and complements), Fashion, Availability of credit, Population, and Expectations of price changes.
let’s explore how these determinants of demand can shift the demand curve to the right:
Determinants of demand and shifting right the demand curve:
- 💰 Income: Higher incomes enable consumers to buy more goods and services, shifting demand curves to the right for normal goods.
- 👍 Tastes (Preferences): Changing preferences towards a product increase demand as more consumers desire it, shifting the demand curve to the right.
- 📢 Advertising: Effective advertising increases consumer awareness and desire, shifting the demand curve to the right.
- 🔄 Prices of Other Goods (Substitutes and Complements):
- Substitutes: Higher prices of substitutes increase demand for the original product, shifting its demand curve to the right.
- Complements: Lower prices of complements increase demand for both goods, shifting their demand curves to the right.
- 👗 Fashion: Trends and fashion shifts increase demand for trendy goods, shifting their demand curves to the right.
- 🏙️ Population: Growth in population increases overall demand for goods and services, shifting their demand curves to the right.
- 💳 Availability of Credit: Easy access to credit allows consumers to buy more, shifting demand curves to the right.
- 📈 Expectations of Price Changes: Anticipation of future price increases leads to higher current demand, shifting the demand curve to the right.
let’s explore how these determinants of demand can shift the demand curve to the left:
Determinants of demand and shifting left the demand curve:
- 💸 Income: Lower incomes reduce purchasing power, decreasing demand for normal goods and shifting their demand curves to the left.
- 👎 Tastes (Preferences): Changing preferences away from a product decrease demand as fewer consumers desire it, shifting the demand curve to the left.
- 🚫 Advertising: Ineffective or negative advertising can decrease consumer interest and demand, shifting the demand curve to the left.
- 🔄 Prices of Other Goods (Substitutes and Complements):
- Substitutes: Lower prices of substitutes decrease demand for the original product, shifting its demand curve to the left.
- Complements: Higher prices of complements decrease demand for both goods, shifting their demand curves to the left.
- 🕴️Fashion: Shifts away from a product in fashion decrease demand, shifting its demand curve to the left.
- 👪 Population: Declines or changes in demographics reduce overall demand for goods and services, shifting their demand curves to the left.
- 💳 Availability of Credit: Tightening credit conditions reduce consumer spending, shifting demand curves to the left.
- 📉 Expectations of Price Changes: Anticipation of future price decreases reduces current demand, shifting the demand curve to the left.
Test Your Knowledge with Scenarios
These questions will test your ability to understand and analyse shifts in demand curves. Pay close attention to the details provided in the case study.
Practice drawing demand curves for scenarios like the ones below to prepare effectively 👇
Situation: Due to adverse weather conditions in Brazil, the supply of coffee has decreased, leading to a significant increase in coffee prices worldwide.
Question: "Draw a diagram to show the effect on just the demand for tea of the increased price of coffee, assuming tea and coffee are substitutes."
- Situation: Due to increased fuel costs and regulatory changes, airlines worldwide decide to raise ticket prices for international flights by 15%.
- Question: "Draw a diagram to illustrate the effect of a 15% increase in the price of international airline tickets on the market for air travel."
- Situation: Following a global economic recession, there has been a sharp decline in consumer incomes in developed countries.
- Question: "Using a demand diagram, illustrate the impact of reduced consumer income on the demand for luxury watches."
What is Price Elasticity of Demand (PED)?
- It helps economists and businesses understand how much quantity demanded changes when prices change.
When we talk about PED, we are thinking about how much the demand stretches or changes when prices go up or down.
- If the demand stretches a lot (like a very stretchy rubber band), we say it's elastic.
- If it doesn't stretch much (like a stiff rubber band), it's inelastic.
👉 PED helps us understand how sensitive people are to price changes for different products.
Elasticity affects the slope of a product's demand curve:
- A smaller slope means a flatter demand curve and more elastic product.
- Example: If the price of a laptop goes down by 15% and the demand for laptops is elastic, this means that the quantity demanded for laptops will increase by more than 15%.
An inelastic demand happens when a change in price results in only a small change in the quantity demanded.
- A greater slope means a steeper demand curve and more inelastic product.
- Example: If the price of a laptop goes down by 15% and the demand for laptop is inelastic, this means that the quantity demanded for laptops will increase by less than 15%.
When the price drops from P1 to P2, the effect on quantity demanded is different for elastic and inelastic demand curves.
- For the elastic demand curve, which is flatter, the quantity demanded increases significantly from Q1 to Q2.
- In contrast, for the inelastic demand curve, which is steeper, the same price decrease from P1 to P2 results in a much smaller increase in quantity demanded from Q1 to Q2.
How to calculate PED?
- PED = 1: This means the product has unit elasticity.
- If the price goes up or down by a certain percentage, the quantity demanded will go up or down by the same percentage.
- If the price of a t-shirt goes up by 10%, the quantity demanded will decrease by 10%. Similarly, if the price drops by 5%, the quantity demanded will increase by 5%. 👔
- PED > 1: This means the product is elastic.
- People are very sensitive to price changes, so if the price changes, the quantity demanded changes a lot.
- If the price of movie tickets increases by 20%, the quantity demanded might drop by 30% because people find alternative entertainment options easily. 🎫
- PED between 0 and 1: This means the product is inelastic.
- People are not very sensitive to price changes, so if the price changes, the quantity demanded changes only a little.
- If the price of gasoline rises by 15%, the quantity demanded might only decrease by 5% because people still need to drive to work and school. ⛽️
- Additionally PED is a unit free measure so the answer is expressed as a number
Practice calculating the price elasticity of demand in these following examples:
What are factors that can influence the PED of a product?
Let’s explore each factors in more detail:
Durability
Example: Apple Iphone📱
When Apple launches a new iPhone, it usually comes with a higher price due to new features.
Impact on Demand:
💵 Price Increase: When Apple increases the price of its new iPhone model, let's say from £800 for the previous model to £1000 for the new model, consumers face a higher cost if they want to upgrade.
😐 Consumer Response:
- Elastic Demand: Many consumers may choose to delay upgrading their iPhone or stick with their current model for longer because the price increase makes the new iPhone less affordable.
- Some might wait for discounts or promotions instead of buying the new Iphone immediately.
😎 Quantity Demanded Decrease: The delay in purchasing the new iPhone or sticking with the older model illustrates elastic demand.
- The quantity demanded for the new iPhone decreases significantly when the price increases because consumers have the option to postpone their purchase.
Habit-Forming Goods
- For example, cigarettes have inelastic demand because smokers will continue to buy them despite price increases.
- Similarly, alcohol also has inelastic demand because people who regularly drink will continue to purchase it even if prices rise. 🍺
Think about your favourite snack 🍫
If the price of your favourite chocolate bar or soda increased, would you stop buying it, or would you pay the higher price to keep enjoying it during lunch or after school?
- Habit-forming goods like these often have inelastic demand because people will continue to purchase them to maintain their daily routines and satisfy their cravings.
Availability of substitutes
Example: Think about soft drinks 🥤
There are many brands and flavours of soft drinks available and various store brands, providing plenty of substitutes.
👉 If the price of Coca-Cola increases, people might buy Pepsi or another soft drink instead
- This means the quantity demanded for Coca-Cola would decrease significantly because consumers have many other choices.
👉 On the other hand, if a good doesn't have a lot of substitutes, people won't have many choices if the price goes up.
- For example, life-saving medications like insulin have very few substitutes. If the price of insulin increases, the quantity demanded wouldn't change much because consumers don't have other options to turn to. This makes the demand for such goods less elastic. 💊
Percentage of Income Spent
👉 If a product takes up a small percentage of income, its demand tends to be inelastic.
👉If a product takes up a large percentage of income, its demand is more elastic.
Examples:
- Inelastic Demand: Items like a pack of pens have low prices relative to income. A price increase from £2 to £3 (a 50% rise) seems significant, but it's only an extra £1. Most consumers will still buy the pack of pens as usual, so the quantity demanded doesn't change much. 🖊️
- Elastic Demand: A family vacation takes up a large portion of income.Suppose a family vacation costs £3,000. If the price of the vacation increases by 10%, it would now cost £3,300—an additional £300.
- For many families, this £300 increase is significant because it represents a noticeable part of their annual income. This substantial cost increase will likely lead to a decrease in the quantity demanded, as many families may decide to cancel or postpone their vacation plans due to the higher price. 🏝️
Degree of Necessity
The level of necessity for a good determines its elasticity:
- More Necessity, Less Elasticity: The greater the necessity for a product, the less sensitive its demand is to price changes. Consumers prioritise purchasing necessary items, such as critical medications, even if prices rise because these goods are crucial for their health or daily life. 💊
- Luxury products, on the other hand, often have greater elasticity. These are items that people can choose to buy or not based on their disposable income and preferences. 💎
Other factors that can affect PED:
Frequency of Purchase 📅
- If a product is bought frequently, people may be less responsive to price changes because they need it regularly.
- Example: Sofas are not bought often, so people can delay buying them if the price goes up.
Brand Loyalty ❤️
- When consumers prefer a particular brand, they might not respond to price changes because they trust and like that brand.
- Example: If people love Nike shoes, they might keep buying them even if the price increases.
Time Period Since Price Change ⏳
- Over a longer time period, consumers have more time to find alternatives and adjust their buying habits.
- Example: If the price of oil-fired heating goes up, over time people might switch to heat pumps 🔥➔❄️.
How Widely Defined a Good Is 🌐
- The broader the definition of a product, the less responsive consumers are to price changes.
- Example: If the price of "crisps" goes up, people might still buy different brands of crisps. But if only "Walkers crisps" increase in price, consumers might switch to another brand.
Price Elasticity of Demand and Total Revenue
- If ticket prices are too high, fewer people will buy them, leading to lower sales.
- If ticket prices are too low, all tickets might sell out, but revenue might be less than it could be with higher prices.
Taylor needs to find the optimal price to maximise her revenue. Should she sell tickets at a lower price to fill more seats, or at a higher price but sell fewer tickets? PED helps answer this question.
- If the tax is too low, it may not reduce consumption significantly, leading to minimal health benefits and tax revenue.
- Conversely, if the tax is too high, consumers may switch to other products, resulting in decreased sales and potential revenue loss.
Understanding PED helps governments predict how changes in taxes or tariffs will affect consumer behaviour and overall revenue.
Total revenue and Demand
👉 demand is inelastic or elastic
👉 AND whether there is a price increase or decrease.
Let’s consider an example of where demand is elastic and there is a price DECREASE:
Let’s consider an example of where demand is elastic and there is a price INCREASE:
Let’s now consider an example of where demand is inelastic and there is a price DECREASE:
Let’s now consider an example of where demand is inelastic and there is a price INCREASE:
Let’s now consider an example of where demand is unit elastic:
Summary:
- Is the demand elastic or inelastic?
- Is there a price increase or decrease?
- 📈 If the price increases: Demand will decrease.
- 📉 If the price decreases: Demand will increase.
- By how much does demand increase or decrease?
- Elastic Demand:
- Changes in quantity demanded are larger than changes in price.
- Inelastic Demand:
- Changes in quantity demanded are smaller than changes in price.
They found that a 13p levy on every £1 of property value could generate about £57 million annually. This demonstrates how governments plan to increase revenue, considering that alcohol tends to have price inelastic demand—meaning people will generally buy it even if the price increases, affecting how taxes like this are designed and their impact on government income.